Map of areas under the direct authority of the Makhzen (in white) in the early 1900s during a state of rebellion

The Pre-colonial Makhzen (Arabic: المخزن) was the governing institution of pre-colonial Morocco prior to the imposition of the French protectorate as a result of the Treaty of Fes in 1912. The form of government in Morocco was an absolute monarchy, and all political sovereignty belonged to the Sultan of Morocco. The Makhzen governed on the basis of Shari'a Islamic law derived from the Qur'an.[1] The Makhzen operated on a system of Sharifism, in which the shurafā, descendants of prophet Muhammad through his grandson Hasan ibn Ali, held a privileged political and religious position in society.[2] Bilād al-Makhzen ('the land of the makhzen') was the term for the areas under central government authority, while those areas run by autonomous tribal authority were known as Bilād as-Siba ('the land of dissidence').[3]

Etymology

The word makhzen (Arabic: مخزن), meaning "warehouse" in Arabic (from khazana 'to store up'[4]), where the sultan's civil servants used to receive their wages; but this usage of the word became in Moroccan Arabic synonymous with the elite. It is likely a metonymy related to taxes, which the makhzen used to collect.

Administration

Sultan of Morocco Hassan I in 1893

The Empire of Morocco was divided into provinces, and these were divided into districts. Provinces were governed by a qāḍī, while districts were governed by sheikhs. The qāḍīs were appointed by the sultan in the Moroccan capital of Fes. Each village was governed by a muqaddam, who was responsible for order among the governed civilians. Governors were appointed from the most influential people of their tribe or district. Their duty was to levy taxes for the imperial treasury and to maintain order, and could punish by fine, imprisonment or foot whipping. Only the sultan of Morocco had the right to give the direct order of capital punishment.[1] Most of these governors, in addition to the police force, were unpaid officials. It was only until the recommendations and advice of Sir John Drummond Hay during the reign of Sultan Muhammad IV bin Abd al-Rahman (1859-1873) that the plan of paying administrators was introduced, following the Anglo-Moroccan Treaty of 1856, to the great advantage of the treasury. However, great fraud and irregularities remained.[1]

Tribal loyalties

State power was based on a system of personal loyalty to the sultan, which was exchanged for protection. State authority extended to Arab tribes and Berber tribes that pledged allegiance to the Sultan. Pre-colonial Morocco in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries had no clear state boundaries nor clear temporal subjects. There were tribes that refused the sultan's authority and taxes, in areas known as Bilād as-Siba, lawless areas outside the control of the Moroccan sultans. Increasing taxes were often resisted by semi-autonomous tribes and towns, causing rebellions.[5] Arab tribes provided a significant force to the sultan's army. They were known as the Guich, Arab tribes[6] that served as troops and military garrisons, as well as to protect the outskirts of the capital and to suppress rebellions.[7]

Sharifism

The Saadi dynasty revived Sharifism in the 16th century to assert Arab supremacy in Berber regions.[8]The 'Alawite dynasty rose to power in the 17th century through its Sharifian lineage as well as its alliances with shurafā' families in Fes, especially the Idrisid family, descendants of the founder of Fes, Idris II.[9] Beginning during the reign of Sultan Ismail (1672-1727), the Makhzen began to officially document and verify lineages, restricting the number of families that could receive tax cuts and other benefits on the basis of their sharīfī lineage.[9]

References

  1. 1 2 3 Journal of the Society of Arts. Society of Arts. 1877. p. 532.
  2. Bazzaz, Sahar (2010). Forgotten saints : history, power, and politics in the making of modern Morocco. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0-674-03539-3. OCLC 467355120.
  3. Bernard Hours; Pepita Ould Ahmed (10 April 2015). An Anthropological Economy of Debt. Taylor & Francis. pp. 83–84. ISBN 978-1-317-49708-0.
  4. NOAD
  5. Sater, James N. (2016-06-09). Morocco: Challenges to tradition and modernity. Routledge. p. 18. ISBN 978-1-317-57398-2.
  6. III, Edmund Burke (2009-02-15). Prelude to Protectorate in Morocco: Pre-Colonial Protest and Resistance, 1860-1912. University of Chicago Press. p. 268. ISBN 978-0-226-08084-0.
  7. Coulet, Louise (1967). "J. le Coz, Les tribus Guichs au Maroc. Essai de Géographie agraire. Extrait de la revue de Géographie du Maroc". Méditerranée. 8 (3): 256–258.
  8. Gottreich, Emily (2020). Jewish Morocco : a history from pre-Islamic to postcolonial times. London. ISBN 978-1-83860-361-8. OCLC 1139892409.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  9. 1 2 Bazzaz, Sahar (2010). Forgotten saints : history, power, and politics in the making of modern Morocco. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0-674-03539-3. OCLC 467355120.
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.