Fēngjiàn (Chinese: 封建; lit. 'demarcation and establishment') was a governance system in ancient China, whose social structure formed a decentralized system of confederation-like government.[1] The ruling class consisted of the Son of Heaven (king) and aristocracy, and the lower class consisted of commoners categorized into four occupations (or "four categories of the people", namely scholar-officials, peasants, laborers and merchants). Elite bonds through affinal relations and submission to the overlordship of the king date back to the Shang dynasty, but it was the Western Zhou dynasty when the Zhou kings enfeoffed their clan relatives and fellow warriors as vassals. Through the fengjian system, the king would allocate an area of land to a noble, establishing him as the ruler of that region and allowing his title and fief to be legitimately inherited by his descendants. This created large numbers of local domains, which became autonomous states.[2][3]: 7–8
Development
The rulers of these vassal states, known as zhūhóu (諸侯; 'many lords'), had a political obligation to pay homage to the king, but as the central authority started to decline during the Eastern Zhou dynasty, their power began to outstrip that of the royal house and subsequently the states developed into their own kingdoms, reducing the Zhou dynasty to little more than a prestigious name.[4] As a result, Chinese history from the Zhou dynasty (1046 BC–256 BC) to the beginning of the Qin dynasty[5] has been termed a "feudal" period by many Chinese historians, due to the custom of enfeoffment of land similar to that in Medieval Europe. However, scholars have suggested that fengjian otherwise lacks some of the fundamental aspects of feudalism.[6][7] This system is often conflated with Confucianism and also with Legalism.
Each fengjian state was autonomous and had its own tax and legal systems along with its own unique currency and even writing style. The nobles were required to pay regular homage to the king and to provide him with soldiers in a time of war. This structure played an important part in the political structure of the Western Zhou which was expanding its territories in the east. In due course this resulted in the increasing power of the noble lords, whose strength eventually exceeded that of the Zhou kings, leading to dwindling central authority. The vassal states started to ignore the orders of the Zhou court and fight with each other for land, wealth and influence, which eventually disintegrated the authority of the Eastern Zhou into the chaos and violence of the Warring States period, where the great lords ended up proclaiming themselves as kings.[8]
During the pre-Qin period, fengjian represented the Zhou dynasty's political system, and various thinkers, such as Confucius, looked to this system as a concrete ideal of political organization. In particular, according to Confucius, during the Spring and Autumn period the traditional system of rituals and music had become empty and hence his goal was to return to or bring back the early Zhou dynasty political system. With the establishment of the Qin dynasty in 220 BCE, the First Emperor unified the country and abolished the fengjian system, consolidating a new system of administrative divisions called the junxian system (郡縣制, "commandery-county system") or prefectural system, with the establishment of thirty-six prefectures and a rotational system for appointing local officials. There are many differences between the two systems, but one is particularly worth mentioning: the prefectural system gave more power to the central government, since it consolidated power at the political center or the top of the empire's political hierarchy. From the Qin dynasty onward, Chinese literati would find a tension between the Confucian ideal of fengjian and the reality of the centralized imperial system.[8]
After the establishment of the Han dynasty, Confucianism became the reigning imperial ideology and scholars and court officials alike again began to look to the Zhou dynasty fengjian system as an ideal. These scholars advocated incorporating elements of the fengjian system into the junxian system. The Han dynasty emperors ultimately chose to parcel out land to their relatives, thus combining the junxian and fengjian systems.[8]
Four occupations
The four occupations were the shì (士) the class of "knightly" scholars, mostly from lower aristocratic orders, the gōng (工) who were the artisans and craftsmen of the kingdom and who, like the farmers, produced essential goods needed by themselves and the rest of society, the nóng (农/農) who were the peasant farmers who cultivated the land which provided the essential food for the people and tributes to the king, and the shāng (商) who were the merchants and traders of the kingdom.
Zōngfǎ (宗法, Clan Law), which applied to all social classes, governed the primogeniture of rank and succession of other siblings. The eldest son of the consort would inherit the title and retained the same rank within the system. Other sons from the consort, concubines, and mistresses would be given titles one rank lower than their father. As time went by, all of these terms lost their original meanings, yet Zhūhóu (诸侯), Dafu (大夫), and Shi (士) became synonyms for court officials.
The four occupations under the fēngjiàn system differed from those of European feudalism in that people were not born into the specific classes, such that, for example, a son born to a gōng craftsman was able to become a part of the shāng merchant class, and so on.
Beginning in the Han dynasty, the sizes of troops and domains a male noble could command would be determined by his rank of peerage, which from highest to lowest were:
- gōng 公
- hóu 侯
- bó 伯
- zǐ 子
- nán 男
While before the Han dynasty an aristocrat with a place name in his title actually governed that place, it was only nominally true afterwards. Any male member of the nobility could be called a gongzi (公子 gōng zǐ), while any son of a king could be called a wangzi (王子 wáng zǐ, i.e. prince).
Well-field system
The well-field system (Chinese: 井田制度; pinyin: jǐngtián zhìdù) was a land distribution method existing in some parts of China between the ninth century BC (late Western Zhou dynasty) to around the end of the Warring States period. Its name comes from Chinese character 井 (jǐng), which means 'well' and looks like the # symbol; this character represents the theoretical appearance of land division: a square area of land was divided into nine identically-sized sections; the eight outer sections (私田; sītián) were privately cultivated by peasants and the center section (公田; gōngtián) was communally cultivated on behalf of the landowning aristocrat.[9]
While all fields were aristocrat-owned,, the private fields were managed exclusively by individual families and the produce was entirely the farmers'. It was only produce from the communal fields, worked on by all eight families, that went to the aristocrats, and which, in turn, could go to the king as tribute.
As part of a larger fēngjiàn system, the well-field system became strained in the Spring and Autumn period[10] as kinship ties between aristocrats became meaningless.[11] When the system became economically untenable in the Warring States period, it was replaced by a system of private land ownership.[10] It was first suspended in the state of Qin by Shang Yang and the other Chinese states soon followed suit.
As part of the "turning the clock back" reformations by Wang Mang during the short-lived Xin dynasty, the system was restored temporarily[12] and renamed to the King's Fields (王田; wángtián). The practice was more-or-less ended by the Song dynasty, but scholars like Zhang Zai and Su Xun were enthusiastic about its restoration and spoke of it in a perhaps oversimplifying admiration, invoking Mencius's frequent praise of the system.[13]
"Feudalism" and Chinese Marxism
Marxist historians in China have described Chinese ancient society as largely feudal.[14][15] The fengjian system is particularly important to Marxist historiographical interpretation of Chinese history in China, from a slave society to a feudal society.[16] The first to propose the use of this term for Chinese society was the Marxist historian and one of the leading writers of 20th-century China, Guo Moruo in the 1930s.[17] Guo Moruo's views dominated the official interpretation of historical records,[18] according to which the political system during the Zhou dynasty can be seen as feudal in many respects and comparable to the feudalistic system in medieval Europe. Guo Moruo based his application of this term on two assumptions:
The first assumption was that feudalism was a form of social organization which arises under certain circumstances, mainly the deterioration of a centralized form of government which is replaced by independent vassal states owing only minimal duties and loyalty to a central ruler. This situation is supposed to have prevailed in China after the decline of the Shang dynasty and the conquering of Shang territories by the Zhou clan. One of the reasons for the shift to feudal states is claimed to be the introduction of iron metallurgy.
The second assumption for classifying the Zhou as feudal by Guo Moruo was the similarity of the essential elements of feudalism that included the granting of land in the form of 'fiefs' to the aristocracy, as was the case of European feudalism. There land fiefs were granted by lords or the monarch to knights, who were considered the 'vassals', who in return promised loyalty to the lord and provided military support during periods of war. In China, instead of a salary, each noble was given land by the Zhou ruler along with the people living on it who worked on the land and gave part of the produce they raised to the nobles as a tax. These 'fiefs' were granted through elaborate ceremonies during the Western Zhou period, where the plots of land, title and rank were granted in formal symbolic ceremonies which were incredibly lavish and which are comparable to the homage ceremonies in Europe where the vassal took the oath of loyalty and fidelity when being granted land that was also called a 'fief'. These ceremonies in the Zhou dynasty were often commemorated in inscriptions on bronze vessels, many of which date back to the early part of the period. Some bronze vessel inscriptions also confirm involvement of military activity in these political arrangements.
Comparisons
Under the Zhou fengjian society, the delegation of authority was based on kinship and there was a single direction of obligation, whereas in the European model, the lord and vassal had clearly specified mutual obligations and duties.[19] Medieval European feudalism realized the classic case of the 'noble lord' while, in the middle and latter phases of the Chinese fengjian society, the landlord system was instead to be found.[18] In Europe, the feudal lordships were hereditary and irrevocable and were passed on from generation to generation, whereas the Zhou lordships were not always hereditary, required reappointment by the king, and could be revoked. The medieval serf was bound to the land and could not leave or dispose of it, whereas the Zhou peasant was free to leave or, beginning in the Eastern Han dynasty, to purchase the land in small parcels.
Moreover, in Europe, feudalism was also considered to be a hierarchical economic system in which the lords were at the top of the structure, followed by the vassals, and then the peasants who were legally bound to the land and were responsible for all production. In Zhou rule, the fengjian system was solely political and was not responsible for governing the economy.
Furthermore, according to China-A New History by John K. Fairbank and Merle Goldman, dissimilarities existed between the merchant class of the two systems as well.[20] In feudal Europe, the merchant class saw a marked development in towns located away from the influence of the manors and their attached villages. The European towns could grow outside of the feudal system instead of being integrated into it since the landed aristocrats were settled in manors. Thus, the towns and their people were independent of the influence of the feudal lords and were usually solely under the political authority of the monarchs of the European kingdoms. In China, these conditions were non-existent and the king and his officials depended greatly on the regional lords for all governance, within towns and without, except in the royal demesne. Thus no independent political power existed to encourage the growth of the merchant class in an independent manner, although exceptions existed and some private individuals could become very wealthy.[21] Chinese towns and villages were part of a fully integrated political system and the merchants remained under the political control of the aristocracy instead of setting up an independent trading or mercantile economy.[22]
Regardless of the similarities of an overwhelmingly agrarian society being dominated by the feudal lords in both societies, the application of the term 'feudal' to the society of the Western Zhou has been a subject of considerable debate due to the differences between the two systems. The Zhou fengjian system was termed as being 'protobureaucratic'[23] and bureaucracy existed alongside feudalism, while in Europe, bureaucracy emerged as a counter system to the feudal order.
Therefore, according to some historians, the term "feudalism" is not an exact fit for the Western Zhou political structure but it can be considered a system somewhat analogous to the one that existed in medieval Europe. According to Terence J. Byres in Feudalism and Non European Societies, "feudalism in China no longer represents a deviation from the norm based on European feudalism, but is a classic case of feudalism in its own right."[24] According to Li Feng, the term "feudalism" is not at all an apt descriptor for the Western Zhou political structure, due to differences in the relationship between the monarch and regional lords, differences in governance of regional states, contrasts in military organization, and the absence of an ordered system of ranks.[25]
See also
References
- ↑ Murthy, Viren (2006). "Modernity against modernity: Wang Hui's critical history of Chinese thought". Modern Intellectual History. Cambridge Univ Press. 3 (1): 137–165. doi:10.1017/S147924430500065X. S2CID 144009226.
- ↑ "Xi 24". Zuozhuan. Translated by Steven Durrant; Wai-yee Lee; David Schaberg. University of Washington Press. 2016 [c. 300 BCE]. pp. 380–381. ISBN 9780295999159.
昔周公弔二叔之不鹹,故封建親戚以蕃屏周。"
"Formerly, Duke of Zhou grieved that the two younger brothers (Guan Shu Xian & Cai Shu Du) were not in accord with him. That is why he enfeoffed (封; fēng) and established (建; jiàn) kinsmen and relatives as a hedge and a screen for Zhou - ↑ Pulleyblank, Edwin G. (2000). "Ji 姬 and Jiang 姜: The Role of Exogamic Clans in the Organization of the Zhou Polity" (PDF). Early China. Cambridge University Press. 25: 1–27. doi:10.1017/S0362502800004259. JSTOR 23354272. S2CID 162159081. Archived from the original (PDF) on 18 November 2017.
- ↑ Levenson, Joseph R.; Schurmann, Franz (1969). China-An Interpretive History: From the Beginnings to the Fall of Han. Berkeley: University of California Press. pp. 34–36. ISBN 0-520-01440-5.
- ↑ "Zhou Dynasty (1045-256 BC) – Chinese History: Ancient China Facts". 9 May 2011.
- ↑ "History of Zhou Dynasty". China Education Center. 2004. Retrieved 23 October 2015.
- ↑ Ulrich Theobald. "Chinese History - Zhou Dynasty 周". chinaknowledge.de. Retrieved 23 October 2015.
- 1 2 3 Roberts 1999, pp. 9–12
- ↑ Fu 1981, p. 7
- 1 2 Fu 1981, p. 9
- ↑ Lewis 2006, p. 142
- ↑ Fu 1981, p. 12
- ↑ Bloom 1999, pp. 129–134
- ↑ Dirlik 1985, pp. 198–9
- ↑ "The History of Zhou Dynasty". China Scientific Book Services.
- ↑ Wang, Q. Edward (2000). "Between Marxism and Nationalism: Chinese historiography and the Soviet influence, 1949–1963". Journal of Contemporary China. Taylor & Francis. 9 (23): 95–111. doi:10.1080/1067056001120.
- ↑ Roberts 1999
- 1 2 Byres & Mukhia 1985, pp. 213, 214
- ↑ Li Feng (2003). ""Feudalism" and Western Zhou China: a criticism". Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies. Harvard-Yenching Institute. 63 (1): 115–144. doi:10.2307/25066693. JSTOR 25066693.
- ↑ Fairbank, John; Goldman, Merle (1992). China: A New History. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0-674-01828-1.
- ↑ Yan Qinghua (严清华); Fang Xiaoyu (方小玉) (2009). "Xian Qin liang Han shangren fenzhan zhi bianqian ji qi zhengce fenxi" 先秦两汉商人分层之变迁及其政策分析 (PDF). Wuhan University Journal (in Chinese). 62 (3): 346–352.
- ↑ Fairbank & Goldman 1992
- ↑ Roberts (1999).
- ↑ Byres & Mukhia 1985, p. 218
- ↑ Li (2008), p. 290.
Bibliography
- Bloom, I. (1999). "The evolution of Confucian tradition in antiquity". In De Bary, William Theodore; Chan, Wing-tsit; Lufrano, Richard John; Adler, Joseph (eds.). Sources of Chinese Tradition. Vol. 2. New York: Columbia University Press.
- Byres, Terence; Mukhia, Harbans (1985). Feudalism and Non European Societies. Bristol: Stonebridge Press. ISBN 0-7146-3245-7.
- Dirlik, Arif (1985). Feudalism and Non European Societies. London: Frank Cass and Co. ISBN 0-7146-3245-7.
- Lewis, Mark Edward (2006). The Construction of Space in Early China. Albany: State University of New York Press.
- Fu Zhufu (1981). "The economic history of China: Some special problems". Modern China. 7 (1): 3–30. doi:10.1177/009770048100700101. S2CID 220738994.
- Li Feng (2008). Bureaucracy and the State in Early China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-88447-1.
- Roberts, John A.G. (1999). A Concise History of China. First United Kingdom. ISBN 0-674-00074-9.
- Wu Ta-k'un (1952). "An Interpretation of Chinese Economic History". Past & Present. 1 (1): 1–12. doi:10.1093/past/1.1.1.